Edition 12 - November, 2002

Pharmaceutical bio-prospecting: What conditions are needed for a North-South partnership?

Past and present bio-prospecting contracts show us that determining the nature of a North/South bio-prospecting relationship depends largely on the position of each group of stakeholders. Analysing the apparently diverging interests within the framework of the competitive market theory and in the context of other economic developments can be useful for understanding existing situations and identifying the conditions necessary for a successful North/South partnership.

This approach responds to the following questions:

The concept of partnership

Partnership can be defined as a relationship in which each stakeholder benefits equitably. The benefits and advantages should enable the stakeholders to reach a better, more independent position. A bio-prospecting partnership can mean facilitated access to biodiversity for northern companies and access to technology resources or capacity building for southern stakeholders.

From the theoretical equilibrium of the competitive market to a practical imbalance

The competitive market theory states that optimum equilibrium is obtained when the supply meets the solvable demand, if a certain number of hypotheses are met. But because these hypotheses are not verified, the competitive market cannot ensure an equitable balance in bio-prospecting activities.

  1. First hypothesis: The economic agents are rational and maximise their individual profits
    While pharmaceutical companies are economic agents, it is not sufficient to designate the suppliers as pure economic agents. Indeed, they are states, which have above all a regulating role, and local communities, whose social organisation is not generally based on the commercial use of biodiversity and individual relations.
  2. Second hypothesis: The object exchanged is merchandise that is divisible, private and economically valuable
    However, biodiversity is a specific good. First, it is not indefinitely divisible because biodiversity elements are interdependent. Second, the status of biodiversity depends on international conventions (TRIPS, Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, CBD, Convention on Biological Diversity and ITPGR, International Treaty on Plant Genetic Resources). Third, the economic value of biodiversity is highly uncertain. It cannot take into account the principle of irreversibility and is not able to reflect the social, cultural and local values developed by communities.
  3. Third hypothesis: The atomicity of the agents
    In reality, the exchange of biodiversity results from a negotiation process in which the North disposes of a certain strength in terms of industrial concentration, intellectual property rights (IPR) and availability of information and experts. The northern stakeholders, therefore, influence the prices and exchange conditions.

    These elements show us the limits of the market in ensuring equitable sharing between the North and the South.

Co-ordination tools: keys for leading the market to an optimum balance

Co-operation can make the competitive market equilibrium more profitable and equitable.

1. From competition to co-operation

This graph presents two stakeholders and represents the different choices of capital accumulation they can make: the North accumulates technologies and the South biodiversity. The relationship between the two resources is positive: the North’s investment in technology will depend on the South’s investment in biodiversity and vice versa because biodiversity is understood as raw material and technology as the means to transform it into an end product. This positive relation enables us to explain the existence of two equilibriums on the graph.

2. Key condition: building coordination tools

In order to get stakeholders to abandon a competitive logic and enter into a co-operation scheme, confidence is required, so the creation of co-ordination and communication tools is a key condition.

The stakeholders have to organise their representation in such a way that it enables them to defend their interests with similar power. These representatives are in charge of building institutions for discussions and exchanges of ideas under equal conditions, which means that the voices are of equal importance. Agreements and conventions then give decisions a legally binding strength. They must be clear and unequivocal.

Thus, the co-ordination tools result from the capacity and the choice of the stakeholders.

The partnership and its co-ordination tools today: criticism and perspectives

The last ten years have shown us an increase of international awareness of the need to build partnerships. Indeed, stakeholders’ associations such as non-governmental organisations are taking an active part in the process. Institutions have been created, and the CBD and its implementation tools – such as mutually agreed terms to be cast in Material Transfer Agreements (MTA) – are intended to promote equitable access and benefit sharing (ABS).

  1. Have these coordination tools really been built to ensure a confident North/South relation and equitable benefit sharing?
    The imbalance between some economic institutions and conventions and others promoting access and benefit sharing seems to maintain and not reduce the North-South gap. The three following points illustrate this imbalance. First, while the World Trade Organisation can enforce its decisions and impose its rules to the members, the CBD institutions have no control over the implementation of their principles. Another example of imbalance lies between the strong degree of obligation of the IPR and the weakness of the CBD. And, finally, the unclear relationship between CBD and IPR promotes conflicts and not co-operation between the stakeholders.
  2. Perspectives of a partnership?
    The existing co-ordination tools are a necessary and good basis for any future improvements in the building of a partnership. However, these tools and consequently the partnership depend on the capacity and will of the stakeholders to create adequate conditions. Today, this partnership faces two obstacles: the reluctance of the North to insert an explicit sharing obligation in the IPR and the difficulty of the South to ensure partnership among the southern stakeholders.

Conclusion

The difficulty in building a partnership results from a misunderstanding of the concept itself. Instead of considering partnership as a source of opportunities and growth, the stakeholders often view it as a complex relationship that weakens the protection of their individual interests. The solution is to convince the stakeholders of the profitability and advantages of a partnership.

Authors:
Stéphanie FRIEBEL, Bachelor in Commercial and Consular Sciences
Philippe Desmeth, BCCM International Programme Officer

This article is based on Bio-prospecting in the pharmaceutical sector: a partnership between North and South? by Stéphanie Friebel

 

BCCM HomeBCCM
Home
Contents
Edition 12 - November, 2002
Next Article
Edition 12 - November, 2002